Keywords
commercial influences on health, unhealthy commodities, public health
Increased taxation is recognised worldwide as one of the most effective interventions for decreasing tobacco and harmful alcohol use, with many variations of policy options available. This rapid scoping review was part of a NIHR-funded project (‘SYNTAX’ 16/105/26) and was undertaken during 2018 to inform interviews to be conducted with UK public health stakeholders with expertise in alcohol and tobacco pricing policy.
Objectives: To synthesise evidence and debates on current and potential alcohol and tobacco taxation options for the UK, and report on the underlying objectives, evidence of effects and mediating factors.
Eligibility criteria: Peer-reviewed and grey literature; published 1997–2018; English language; UK-focused; include taxation interventions for alcohol, tobacco, or both.
Sources of evidence: PubMed, Scopus, Cochrane Library, Google, stakeholder and colleague recommendations.
Charting methods: Excel spreadsheet structured using PICO framework, recording source characteristics and content.
Ninety-one sources qualified for inclusion: 49 alcohol, 36 tobacco, 6 both. Analysis identified four policy themes: changes to excise duty within existing tax structures, structural reforms, industry measures, and hypothecation of tax revenue for public benefits. For alcohol, policy options focused on raising the price of cheap, high-strength alcohol. For tobacco, policy options focused on raising the price of all tobacco products, especially the cheapest products, which are hand-rolling tobacco. For alcohol and tobacco, there were options such as levies that take money from the industries to help reduce the societal costs of their products. Due to the perceived social and economic importance of alcohol in contrast to tobacco, policy options also discussed supporting pubs and small breweries.
This review has identified a set of tax policy options for tobacco and alcohol, their objectives, evidence of effects and related mediating factors. The differences between alcohol and tobacco tax policy options and debates suggest an opportunity for cross-substance policy learning.
Why we did it: Alcohol and tobacco cause many diseases and deaths. People who drink heavily are more likely to be smokers. People who smoke and drink heavily are more likely to get ill and die sooner. Increasing alcohol and tobacco taxes has been shown to reduce their consumption. Research was needed to understand how and why alcohol and tobacco tax might be changed. This rapid scoping review was undertaken during 2018 as part of a National Institute for Health and Care Research funded project called ‘SYNTAX’ (16/105/26). Its main purpose was to inform interviews to be conducted with UK public health stakeholders with expertise in alcohol and tobacco pricing policy.
Why we did it: We looked at academic papers and policy reports published between 1997 and 2018 that discussed or estimated the effects of changes to tax on alcohol and tobacco.
What we found: The results of the review summarise the options for changing alcohol and tobacco taxes that were being considered in the UK, and why.
What this means: Some options for changing tax were the same for alcohol and tobacco, but there were also differences between alcohol and tobacco, which reflected differences in how alcohol and tobacco are viewed in society. We used the findings of the review to prepare to speak to alcohol and tobacco tax experts about the options for changing tax on alcohol and tobacco, which we did in 2018.
commercial influences on health, unhealthy commodities, public health
The revised article takes into account the changing landscape of alcohol and tobacco tax policies in the UK from 2018 to 2023, with Brexit playing a significant role. It discusses recent structural reforms in alcohol taxes and possible adjustments in tobacco taxes.
In the introduction, we improved clarity by refining sentences, addressing grammar issues, defining complex terms, and adding information about changes in alcohol tax structures.
The methods section now provides a more detailed explanation for why we didn't assess the quality of studies in our rapid review, aligning with our specific scoping objectives.
In the results section, we clarified that we categorised sources into those presenting quantitative policy effects and those offering qualitative insights. While we didn't explicitly differentiate between computer model-based and real-world data studies, we enhanced the language used to describe the type of studies that the quantitative effect estimates were derived from.
In the discussion section, we added an explanation for why previous research rarely examined the combined effects of alcohol and tobacco and the potential benefits of doing so. This insight came from a workshop report involving UK academics and policy professionals. The limitations section now explicitly acknowledges the 2018 search end date as a potential limitation due to the dynamic nature of alcohol and tobacco tax policies. We briefly discuss the potential implications of Brexit on alcohol and tobacco taxation. Lastly, we included a new point about not examining non-tax price measures like minimum pricing, highlighting their importance but recognizing their distinction from tax policies.
See the authors' detailed response to the review by Lana Elliott
See the authors' detailed response to the review by G. Emmanuel Guindon
Alcohol and tobacco are major risk factors for a wide range of diseases1,2. To give a sense of the scale of the health burden caused by alcohol and tobacco consumption, in 2016 in England, there were 337,000 alcohol-related hospital admissions, and 484,700 tobacco-related hospital admissions3,4. Furthermore, drinking and smoking are correlated behaviours5, meaning that people who smoke tend to have higher levels of alcohol consumption, and these people consequently spend a high proportion of their budgets on alcohol and tobacco6. Of the available interventions to jointly address alcohol and tobacco related harms7, increasing taxes on alcohol and tobacco is considered among the most effective approaches to improve health8,9. In general, there is evidence that increases in product prices decrease demand10–16, especially in socio-economically disadvantaged groups17–19.
Excise taxes are those levied on selected goods produced for sale in a country or imported and sold in that country. They are imposed by governments mainly as specific excise taxes or ad valorem taxes, and are collected from the producer or manufacturer within a certain time frame (e.g., 20–30 days) after the product has left the factory20. Excise duties are commonly applied to alcohol (155 countries in 2016) and tobacco products (166 countries in 2018) worldwide21,22. As elsewhere, excise duties are applied in the UK after manufacturing. Both alcohol and tobacco products incur specific excise duties (calculated as a fixed tax per specified element of product: e.g., per litre, cigarette stick, gram). Cigarettes also incur ad valorem excise duties (calculated as a percentage of the retail price) and, since 2017, have been subject to a minimum excise duty (set at £293.95 per 1,000 cigarettes at the time that this review was conducted, but having subsequently increased). Since 2010, tobacco excise duty has been increased annually in accordance with a duty escalator of a certain percentage above inflation (the rate of increase in tobacco duty under the escalator has varied over time). The UK Government decided to remove a similar duty escalator for alcohol in 2013 (for beer) and 2014 (for other alcohol products). The report by Angus and Henney23 gives model-based estimates of the impact of the decision to remove the alcohol duty escalator and of the subsequent reductions and freezes in alcohol duty. The rates of excise duties in the UK at the time that this review was conducted can be found in Box 124,25. At that time, UK alcohol and tobacco tax options were constrained by shared European Union (EU) directives on alcohol and tobacco tax26,27, which have since been passed across into UK law. In addition to excise duties, alcohol and tobacco products in the UK are also subject to a 20% tax applied at point of sale (known in the UK as Value Added Tax (VAT)).
[sources:
UK: https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/rates-and-allowances-excise-duty-tobacco-duty/excise-duty-tobacco-duty-rates; https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/rates-and-allowance-excise-duty-alcohol-duty/alcohol-duty-rates-from-24-march-2014,
EU: https://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/business/excise-duties-alcohol-tobacco-energy/excise-duties-alcohol_en; https://ec.europa.eu/taxation_customs/business/excise-duties-alcohol-tobacco-energy/excise-duties-tobacco_en
Since conducting this review, the UK government has decided to introduce changes to the duty structure for alcohol products, creating a standardised series of tax bands based on alcohol by volume and introducing tax relief for small producers and on products sold in the on-trade venues, such as pubs28. These reforms came into effect on 1st August 2023.
The objective of this scoping review was to synthesise evidence and debates on contemporary alcohol and tobacco taxation options for the UK, and to report underlying objectives, observed or predicted effects and mediating factors. It was undertaken to inform subsequent interviews conducted with UK public health stakeholders with expertise in alcohol and tobacco pricing policy. These interviews were undertaken in 2018 as part of the progression of research in the National Institute for Health and Care Research funded ‘SYNTAX’ project (16/105/26)29. The SYNTAX project aimed to produce the evidence required for joint policy analysis of alcohol and tobacco tax policy changes. Therefore, both existing policies and ideas for policy innovation were in scope for this review.
Whilst ethical approval was not required specifically for this scoping review of the literature, this review formed part of work package 1 of the SYNTAX project, which conducted qualitative research on alcohol and tobacco tax policy interventions. Ethical approval for the qualitative research element of work package 1 was obtained from the Sheffield University, UK, Sheffield Centre for Health and Related Research Ethics Committee (ref. 017409, 2018) and confirmed by the REACH Committee at the University of Bath, UK.
We undertook a scoping review of alcohol and tobacco tax policy research in the UK (see Arksey and O’Malley30 for a discussion of the variation in scoping review methods). We followed a modified version of the rapid review approach recommended by Tricco et al.,31,32. This involved searching >1 database, published and grey literature, searches limited by date and language, research scope specified by two researchers in consultation with the SYNTAX project team and a health librarian, study selection by one reviewer only, data abstraction by one reviewer and one verifier. Modifications to suit the scoping nature of our study were inclusion of grey literature (enabling us to gather wider information about tax options) and exclusion of quality appraisal, which was extraneous to the study’s research objectives: namely, to identify and describe policy options for tobacco and/or alcohol tax. Due to the scoping nature of our study, we simply distinguish studies that are qualitative from studies that present policy effect sizes, which could be effect sizes observed from statistical analyses or effect sizes predicted by computer simulation models. Whilst we acknowledge that observed and predicted effect sizes are not equivalent forms of evidence, it was outside the scope of this study to quality appraise and synthesise the effect size evidence. This method was chosen because it simplifies the systematic review process to produce a synthesis of available knowledge more quickly ensuring feasibility and timeliness, while minimising risk of bias31,33. It was also chosen as a way to produce a briefing for policy stakeholders and support policy discussion34. For the study’s full protocol, see Extended data35.
Inclusion was restricted to peer-reviewed and grey literature, including governmental, non-governmental and alcohol and tobacco industry documents, published 1997–2018, written in English. Sources had to include a specific description and/or analysis of one or more historical, current, or prospective taxation interventions for either alcohol, tobacco, or both for the UK. Documents which had a global focus but referred briefly to the UK or referred only to non-specific interventions, such as “increase tax”, were excluded.
Searches were conducted in April 2018 using the PubMed, Scopus and Cochrane Library databases, supplemented by a Google grey literature search. Additional sources proposed by stakeholders and colleagues were located and screened against the inclusion criteria in December 2018.
Search terms used were ((tobacco OR cig* OR alcohol OR beer OR wine OR cider OR spirits) AND (tax OR taxes OR taxation OR excise OR duty) AND (UK OR “United Kingdom” OR Scotland OR England OR Wales OR “Northern Ireland” OR Britain)). Google searches also included (AND pdf) to help restrict the volume of documents arising from the search to reports, rather than webpages. The search process and terms used were discussed with a subject librarian at the University of Bath and agreed by the project team. A summary of searches undertaken and associated results can be found in Extended data35. Search results from databases were extracted directly to the Endnote reference management software (free alternatives such as Mendeley are available). Documents from Google searches, stakeholders and colleagues were recorded in a spreadsheet and transferred manually.
Duplicates were removed automatically using reference management software. Titles and abstracts for the remaining results were screened against the inclusion criteria. Full texts of the remaining documents were screened.
An excel spreadsheet structured according to the PICO framework was used to extract data. The PICO framework is a commonly used model for structuring the key elements of studies in terms of the Population, Intervention, Comparator, Outcome. JH and PB designed and tested the spreadsheet. Data were charted by JH. Charting was monitored via regular peer debriefing with PB and DG and minor modifications were made. For example, additional columns were added to record which categories of tax policy options were referred to in sources as those categories emerged from the data.
Reference information (reference number, title, author, date), type of source, declared funding, aims, methods and findings were charted where information was available. The PICO framework was then used to chart data content as follows. For Population, we charted geographical context, population group and timeframe in which the intervention was posited or implemented, product type and sub-type. For Intervention, we charted the technical description of the tax intervention and objectives. For Comparator, we charted the system of taxation, or aspect of the system, that was or would be changed by the intervention. Finally, for Outcome, we charted primary effects (e.g., product price or consumer behaviour); secondary effects (e.g., on health, social and economic outcomes), differential effects among subgroups, and mediating factors which could impact effectiveness.
Extracted data were synthesised across the data set. Similar taxation interventions were grouped together and described in terms of their objectives, observed or predicted effects and mediating factors. JH used an inductive approach to identify categories within each of these components, and categories were refined via discussion with PB and DG. In each subsection, we report the proportion of sources that were peer-reviewed journal articles. Due to the inclusion of published and grey literature, sources varied widely in the types of evidence they presented or cited. We sought to reflect this variation in the wording of our results by, for example, indicating where cited examples were based on evaluative or predictive studies and by using associated terms such as ‘observed’ or ‘predicted’.
Figure 1 shows the source search record. Database searches returned 731 documents; the Google search returned 58 documents; a further 38 documents were identified through conversations with the project team and stakeholders. After duplicates were removed, 637 documents were screened at the title and abstract stage; and 247 full texts were screened. Of these, 91 sources met the inclusion criteria.
This study’s Extended data35 provides detailed characteristics of all sources included in the study. Included sources were published between 1997 and 2018 and comprised 33 peer-reviewed journal articles and 58 grey literature sources. Methods were described by authors in just over half of sources and were predominantly quantitative in nature (e.g., predictive modelling studies, trends analyses, descriptive analyses). Funding was declared in 62 sources: nearly half of which were funded by government or research councils and only 4 by industry. Alcohol was the focus of 49 sources, 36 were on tobacco, 6 on both alcohol and tobacco.
Policy options identified were grouped thematically into four categories:
1. Changes to excise duty to increase product prices using existing tax structures.
2. Structural reforms to the tax applied to alcohol and tobacco products.
3. Industry measures – tax changes designed to modify the revenue or profits that the alcohol and tobacco industries gain from product sales.
4. Hypothecation motives for changing tax (applied to options 1 to 3 above) – increasing tax in order to spend the revenue on public benefits, especially on initiatives that further the reduction of harmful alcohol and tobacco consumption or mitigate its harmful effects.
Figure 2 and Table 1 show a breakdown of the sources that refer to each of the policy options. In Table 1, the sources indicated in bold presented policy effect sizes, which could be observed from statistical analyses of real-world policy effects or predicted by computer simulation models of policy effects. Observed or predicted effects of the policy options described in the included literature were reported in 48 sources, 23 of which were peer-reviewed journal articles. The nature and evidence of effects are summarised below.
Bold indicates studies that presented policy effect sizes.
Category | Sub-category | No. studies | Alcohol (n=49) | Tobacco (n=36) | Alcohol/ Tobacco (n=6) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Excise duty | Excise duty rates | 37 | 19,36,37,38,46,47,48,49,50,51,52,53,54,55, 56,57,58,59,60 | 39,40,41,42,43,44,45,61,62,63,64,65,66,67,68,69 | 70,71 |
Duty escalators | 33 | 17,46,47,48,55,60,72,73,74,75,76,77,78,79, 80,81,82 | 39,61,65,67,83,84,85,86,87,88,89,90,91,92,93 | 94 | |
Product-specific excise duty | 24 | 19,46,51,53,55,58,74,78,79,80,81,95,96,97 | 64,65,83,86,87,88,90,98,99 | 100 | |
Minimum excise duty | 9 | No data | 64,65,83,86,87,88,90,101,102 | No data | |
Taxation structures | Equivalent taxation (per unit,per gram) | 22 | 36,38,46,48,56,81,82,95,103,104,105,106,107, 108,109,110,111 | 64,90,101,102 | 70 |
Multi-rate taxation (rates set according to product strength or harm) | 22 | 72,74,75,76,46,52,54,55,81,95,103,104,105, 106,111,112,113,114 | 86,89,115 | 94 | |
Supplementary tax (in addition to excise duty & VAT) | 4 | 36,54,116 | No data | 117 | |
International harmonisation (reduce cross-border price gaps) | 4 | 49,96 | 40,86 | No data | |
Industry measures | Industry levy (for retailers or manufacturers) | 12 | No data | 65,86,87,88,89,118,119,120,121 | 70,117,122 |
Wholesale price cap (limiting profitability of manufacturers) | 6 | No data | 90,91,101,102,118,121 | No data | |
Industry subsidy (to support particular producers or retail sectors) | 3 | 72,123,124 | No data | No data | |
Hypothecation | Hypothecation for prevention or treatment services or the NHS | 21 | 38,52,53,116 | 45,61,62,65,66,67,83,86,87,88,92,118,119,120 | 70,117,122 |
Changes to excise duty rates. Thirty-seven sources: Potential changes discussed in the literature ranged from −2% to 34% for alcohol and 2% to 25% for tobacco. Estimates of policy effects were presented in 20 out of 37 sources: 8 alcohol, 11 tobacco and 1 cross-sector (shown in bold in Table 1).
For alcohol, examples in the literature of modelled effects of tax-led price change on population-level consumption include: a 10% price increase leading to a 4.4% reduction in consumption19; a 13.4% increase in all alcohol duty leading to a 1.7% reduction in consumption36. These two studies also examined estimated impacts on particular groups in society and showed consumption was predicted to fall most for ‘hazardous’ and ‘harmful’ drinkers, with the latter likely to incur greatest additional expenditure from the policies. The second study also estimated a shallow socio-economic gradient with those in the lowest quintile predicted to reduce consumption by 2.3% versus 1.1% for the highest quintile. Modelling also showed that tax-related price increases of 1% above inflation are likely to reduce violence-related hospital emergency department visits37,38.
For tobacco, there is observed evidence of reduced cigarette sales39 and consumption40,41 arising from excise duty increases. These effects occur by encouraging quitting and switching behaviours42,43, and can have a greater effect on younger consumers44. For example, a 1% increase in price was reported to reduce consumption by 0.5%41 and modelling has shown that between 1998 and 2010, an estimated 31% of falling tobacco product consumption can be attributed to increased price44. As with alcohol, increased tobacco duty rates may also impact healthcare costs. A modelled tobacco duty increase of 10% in Scotland was predicted to save an estimated £17m in prevented hospitalisations over ten years if the revenue raised was subsequently hypothecated for tobacco control measures targeted at the most deprived quintile45.
Duty escalators. Thirty-three sources: Policy options covered in the literature were duty escalators that increase alcohol and tobacco duty annually by between 2% and 5% above inflation. Estimates of the effects of escalators were presented in 15 out of 33 sources: 10 alcohol and 5 tobacco.
For alcohol, a 2% duty escalator was in place in the UK between 2008 and 2013, enabling effects to be observed rather than modelled. The escalator reduced affordability of alcohol products by between 22% (beer) and 54% (wine)72,73, a trend which reversed after the policy ended72,74. The escalator’s abolition in 2013/14 was observed to decrease alcohol duty in real terms75–77, reduce prices46,78 and increase affordability (particularly of cheap strong drinks and off-trade purchases – e.g. beer was 21.8% more affordable, spirits were 14.2% more affordable)47,74,76,77. It also significantly reduced government revenue70,72,74–76. Despite this evidence, the Scotch Whisky Association predicted that scrapping the duty escalator would create jobs and generate public revenue48.
For tobacco, the duty escalator has been observed to reduce smoking rates among lower income smokers61. Modelled analysis of a 5% above inflation tobacco duty escalator from 2015 estimated that by 2035 prices would be 87.6% (for factory-made cigarettes (FM)) and 78.2% (for hand-rolled tobacco (HRT)) higher than under the existing 2% escalator83. The relative effects of duty increases and escalators were compared in 13 sources. Hospital admissions and mortality rates have been shown to be affected by both alcohol and tobacco duty rates and escalators45–47,49,62,72,73,84. These policy options also generate revenue61,63,84,85 and long-term savings to society45,47,50,83.
Change duty rates on specific products. Twenty-four sources: Policy options for alcohol included raising excise rates on stronger and more harmful ciders, beers, spirits and wines, and alcohol products retailing at less than £0.30 per unit. For tobacco, measures included raising excise duty rates 2% above inflation for FM and 5–10% above inflation for HRT and pipe tobacco in order to close the price gap with FM. Estimates of effects were presented in 4 out of 24 sources: 1 alcohol and 3 tobacco.
For alcohol, one modelling study showed the effect of using tax to increase the price of products retailing at <£0.30 per unit by 25%19. For on-trade products, the model predicted a fall of 1.3% in overall consumption, with hazardous drinkers most affected and a small increase in spending of £3.10–£24.00 per annum per drinker. For off-trade products, the model predicted a fall of 0.6% in overall consumption, with hazardous drinkers most affected and a small increase in spending of £2.10–£37.80 per annum per drinker.
For tobacco, evidence relates to HRT: a 2011 duty increase on HRT increased prices, narrowing the price gap with FM64. This is important because increases in the UK’s tax gap between FM and HRT are associated with an increase in the proportion and number of smokers who smoke HRT98 and increased product price is expected to reduce smoking uptake83.
Minimum excise tax (MET). Nine sources: MET was introduced in the UK in 2017 for FM. It sets a minimum level of excise duty based on the weighted average price of tobacco. The intention of the policy was that the minimum level of excise duty is uprated annually at every budget. At the time of our search there were no papers examining the actual effects of MET. However, 6 papers raised the possibility of introducing a minimum consumption tax. This would extend MET to include value added tax (VAT) and would thereby impact on the price of HRT64,65,84,86–88.
Equivalent taxation. Twenty-two sources: Equivalent taxation is where a universal rate of duty is applied per unit for alcohol or per gram for tobacco. Estimates of effects were presented in 3 out of 22 sources: 2 alcohol and 1 cross-sector. For alcohol, a per unit tax was estimated to slightly reduce alcohol spending overall, with declines in all but those with the highest incomes36,70, although one grey literature paper estimated that the policy would raise tax revenue overall103. A per unit tax was also estimated to lead to a reduction in alcohol-related mortality among consumers, particularly those on lower incomes36,70. For tobacco, research has begun to explore a move towards a fully specific (per gram) tax structure helping to harmonise tobacco product duty rates – at the time of the review the EU Tobacco Tax Directive required that duty rates are comprised by a combination of ad valorem (percentage of retail price) and specific (per gram) taxes.
Multi-rate tax structures. Twenty-two sources: Multi-rate taxation structures apply different tax rates dependent on product type or strengths. Examples include scaled volumetric taxation72,75,76, strength-related tax tiers72,75,95,112 and a duty band for heated tobacco products86,89,115. Taxes might also be structured to maximise revenue return51. Looking across alcohol and tobacco, one paper suggested restructuring fiscal policies for unhealthy commodities by coordinating tax and pricing policy across food, soft drinks, alcohol and tobacco94. Estimates of effects were presented in 6 out of 22 sources: 6 alcohol. For alcohol, the >7.5% Alcohol By Volume (ABV; a measure of alcoholic strength) and <2.8% ABV beer tax bands implemented in the UK in 2011 were predicted to have only a small effect on affordability due to the relatively small volume of beer sold in these duty brackets and due to the premium prices of high strength craft beers104,105. Similarly, the 2019 6.9–7.5%ABV cider tax band set at £50.71 per hectolitre was predicted to increase the price of a 3 litre bottle of cider by only 31p (or 9%)76. UK multi-rate tax structures for beer and cider were observed to have reduced the market share of high-strength products and increased that of low-strength products72. Further, modelling has shown that taxing strong spirits at a relatively high rate is an effective way to reduce alcohol volume purchased by heavy drinkers without imposing large costs on lighter drinkers95.
Supplementary tax. Four sources: A supplementary, or added, tax could be introduced in addition to excise duty. Estimates of effects were presented in 3 out of 4 sources: 2 alcohol, 1 cross-sector. For alcohol, a 4% ad valorem alcohol sales tax (or retail excise duty) on product value added after duty at time of purchase (i.e., applied at the same time as VAT). The 4% was predicted to prompt small changes in expenditure with little subgroup variation36. A 2p per unit ring-fenced treatment tax on off-trade sales was predicted to add 4p to a pint, 18p to a bottle of wine and 56p to a standard bottle of spirits, raising c. £155m p.a. 2015–17, £290m p.a. 2018–20; £410m p.a. 2021–23; £520m p.a. 2024 onwards116. While a 2.5% consequential impact tax on the purchase price of ‘lifestyle self-abuse’ goods was predicted to raise £0.45bn on tobacco and £2.32bn on alcohol and a related 15% tax on advertising and sponsor spend was predicted to raise £120m117.
International harmonisation. Four sources: International harmonisation of tax rates and/or structure between nation states was examined in 4 sources. For alcohol, options were the introduction of minimum European tax levels on alcoholic beverages49 and joining the World Wine Trade Group to harmonise standards with other wine-exporting countries and lower trade costs96. For tobacco, tax rates could be harmonised across borders, to ensure FM and HRT equivalence and implement minimum excise levels as with the UK’s MET40,86. There was also a proposal to include raw tobacco in the Tobacco Tax Directive as an excisable product86. No sources reported on observed or estimated effects of harmonisation.
Three main categories of industry measures were identified, with these being discussed more frequently for tobacco than for alcohol.
Industry levies. Ten sources: Industry levies were discussed for tobacco and for alcohol and tobacco together. A levy is a cost levied on manufacturers or retailers of alcohol or tobacco products as a percentage of revenue or profit in addition to excise duty and VAT. For tobacco, a levy could be implemented in four ways. (1) As a surcharge on corporation tax: 28% or 33% as per banking sector, user fee, or licensing charge86,87. (2) As a profit-based levy targeted at UK market operations which might reduce industry incentives to maximise profits and invest in marketing118. (3) As a revenue-based levy, entailing a fee per stick or a proportion of total sales revenue by company118. (4) As a fixed tax revenue levy raising £500m total with proportion allocated on sales volume65,87–89,119,120. For alcohol and tobacco, a levy could comprise a 15% tax on industry spend on advertising and sponsorship, reducing industry incentives to produce and promote products and estimated to generate £194m per annum117. Or it could be introduced in the form of a public health supplement as trialled in Scotland where a 13% levy was imposed on large retailers (rateable value >£300,000) selling both alcohol and tobacco products122.
Wholesale price cap accompanied with a rise in excise duty. Six sources: A small group of papers introduced the novel idea of a price cap on tobacco products. This option would involve a limit placed on the wholesale price at which manufacturers can sell their products to retailers. This measure would have to be combined with an equivalent excise duty rise to prevent the retail price from falling90,91,101,102,118,121. The aim of this measure would be to reduce manufacturer profits and increase the price of the cheapest products through the rise in excise duty. It has been estimated that a system of price-cap regulation in the UK would raise around £500 million per year121.
Subsidies. Seven sources: For alcohol only, the literature examined the role of industry or sector subsidies implemented via the excise duty system to encourage or discourage particular businesses or products. An example of this is the existing Small Breweries Relief, where initial production of 0–5000hl attracts a 50% duty cut, with a sliding scale up to 60,000hl104,123,124. For beer, the small brewery subsidy introduced in the UK in 2002 was found to increase short- (but not long-) term profits and may have increased entry into the market, but did not have an effect on survivorship123,124. A similar duty relief for small cider producers could also be introduced72. A more novel idea is to introduce tax incentives for the on-trade, for example via a differential beer duty or lower rate of VAT for draft beer, which has been found to be likely to have a negligible or small impact on tax receipts but to impact consumption at an individual level among male drinkers aged 35+ from lower socio-economic groups46.
Twenty-one sources: As with industry measures, hypothecation interventions were discussed more frequently for tobacco than for alcohol. Hypothecation would see revenue from excise duties, industry levies, or other tax ‘hypothecated’– i.e., reserved – for a particular purpose (e.g., for spending on alcohol or tobacco treatment services or for the National Health Service (NHS)). For alcohol, options explored in the literature included the additional revenue from tax increases being hypothecated for support for families affected by alcohol use, particularly those on low incomes or to offset NHS costs of alcohol-related harm38,52,53. A more specific proposal was for the introduction of a ring-fenced treatment tax on every unit of alcohol sold off-trade to fund effective abstinence-based rehabilitation centres116. For tobacco, similarly, tobacco tax revenues could be hypothecated for the NHS or for treatment and cessation services45,62,66,67,83,86,92. Allocating tobacco duty revenue to the NHS has been shown to be likely to have positive health effects, generating additional quality-adjusted life years83. Revenue from industry levies could be hypothecated in the same way61,65,70,86–89,118–120. Finally, revenue from a cross-cutting consequential impact tax or Public Health Supplement would increase overall revenue which could be hypothecated for a specific purpose. For example, it is argued that the revenue generated by a consequential impact tax (£2.5bn p.a.) would enable the NHS to tackle costs of consumption, with potential greatest effect on lower socio-economic groups117. When implemented, Scotland’s Public Health Supplement raised £95.9m over three years, but the hypothecation element of the policy was ultimately dropped122.
Eighty-four sources referred to one or more objective for changing tax on alcohol or tobacco, of which 29 were peer reviewed journal articles. Objectives were grouped thematically into five categories (Table 2). First, changing product affordability, including price and relative price (23 sources). Second, changing consumer behaviour, including changing consumption and supporting consumers to quit or change their consumption (47 sources). Third, changing health outcomes, including reducing and preventing harm and reducing health inequalities (45 sources). Fourth, changing economic outcomes, such as raising revenue and reducing financial costs to society, also known as externalities (40 sources). Fifth, changing industry behaviour (26 sources). This category included objectives relating to restricting industry – reducing illicit trade, industry profits and industry manipulation of pricing to reduce the intended effects of tax policy. It also included objectives which were more sympathetic to industry including supporting industry and encouraging product reformulation.
In terms of the relationship between the types of tax policy options and specific objectives, all four options were perceived as aiming to change economic outcomes and support consumers for both alcohol and tobacco (Table 2). Excise duties and structural tax reforms were perceived to change affordability and consumption, again for both substances. In relation to industry measures, objectives concerning reducing illicit trade and tackling industry pricing strategies were only mentioned in tobacco sources while objectives concerning incentivising product reformulation and supporting industry were only mentioned in alcohol sources.
Policy mediators were identified in 81 sources (52 grey, 29 peer reviewed). We grouped these thematically into four categories: politics and society (35 sources); policy mix (36 sources); consumers (24 sources); industry (24 sources) (see Extended data35 and described below). Much of the commentary on mediators was general. Where it is specific to alcohol or tobacco, or to a particular type of intervention, this is indicated in the text.
Thirty-five sources: Alcohol and tobacco tax policy debates and decisions were reported to be influenced by economic arguments44,73,78,106, perceptions of public acceptability and historical precedent49,50,54,67,71,72,92,94,112,121, and by narratives regarding potential regressive effects117. Public, medical and political support for tax interventions50,70,72,87,107,108,112,117,119,122 and government buy-in to evidence on health benefits of tax measures113,114,116 were regarded as important for policy action. For alcohol, political narratives mediate against tax increases: social importance of the pub trade79,104, political and economic importance of the industry55,78,104, need to protect the ‘moderate’ or ‘responsible’ drinker19,52,104,105, and the idea that tax is a barrier to investment, reduces sales and costs jobs48,52. Industry influence can perpetuate these narratives and tax policy outcomes via partnerships with government (alcohol) or non-industry bodies (tobacco), lobbying, campaigns, arguments and legal action17,39,52,61,74,76,79,101,113,114,118. Brown identified industry power as “one of the biggest barriers” to tackling the affordability of alcohol17. For tobacco, political leadership and public opinion were considered to have supported sustained tax rises in the UK since the 1990s and may lead to the introduction of new measures such as levies39,92. Overall, more alcohol than tobacco sources considered politics and society to be a barrier to tax interventions (9 tobacco, 21 alcohol, 5 mixed).
Thirty-six sources: Synchronising alcohol and tobacco tax changes with investment in prevention, education, enforcement of minimum age policies and treatment might increase effectiveness in reducing consumption and associated harms39,44,45,62,67,68,71,84,99,112,119. Investing in enforcement efforts and sanctions (e.g. Trading Standards Agency) can discourage illicit trade40,43,48,61,63,71,84,90,99. At the structural level, EU regulations have restricted government freedom to change alcohol and tobacco tax rates and structures or to introduce levies46,56,70,83,101,103–106,109,118,124. However, ‘Brexit’ (Britain’s exit from the European Union) may facilitate a review of these restrictions and could lead to higher prices on imported alcohol products55,70,72,96.
Twenty-four sources: Alcohol and tobacco tax effectiveness is dependent on consumer responses37,41–43,57,63,67,68,71,78,97,105,110. For example, demand is affected by income, prosperity, poverty, age, gender and level of drinking19,37,41,47,63,85. Demand is also affected by the wider economic context (e.g. by recession)50,69,77. Consumers may mediate excise duty changes by changing the products they consume (e.g. cheaper but not necessarily weaker alcohol products, higher tar or nicotine cigarettes, cheaper brands or forms of tobacco such as HRT, bulk buying in carton packs)19,43,63,68,90,95,98,105. Consumers may also change their purchasing practices (e.g. supermarkets not convenience stores, duty-free, social network or illicit sources, where enforcement does not limit availability)68,71,90,93. Finally, consumers may change how they consume, for example smoking less cigarettes more intensively63,68.
Twenty-four sources: Industry mediate tax policy post-implementation via tax pass-through and pricing strategies43,56,58,61,63,80,86,98,101,102,110,113. Modifying the tax pass-through to product sales prices can take two forms: “under-shifting” in which industry decreases the profits that they make from product sales in order to mitigate the effects of tax increases on product sales prices; “over-shifting” in which industry increases the profits that they make from product sales at the same time as a tax increase, which could act to mitigate any lost profits from decreases in consumer demand (see Wilson et al.125,126 for recent analyses of tax pass-through for alcohol and tobacco in the UK). For example, producers (and retailers for alcohol) under-shift tax onto cheaper products and over-shift tax onto premium products, widening the gap between them47,53,64,71,79–81,83,90,100,111. Supermarkets shift alcohol tax rises onto non-alcohol products (i.e. loss-leading)53,56. Multi-national companies can offset lost profits in the UK in other markets102. Companies can reduce their duty liability by modifying their timetable for tax clearance (e.g. releasing more product for sale before a duty escalator increase)75,100. Concern was expressed that small incremental tax increases can drive industry profits as they support the industry’s pricing strategy91. For alcohol, attempts to support profitability of small and medium sized businesses via the tax system are unlikely to be successful when supply chains are dominated by more powerful businesses123. Industry also mediate tax via product reformulation and marketing72,112. For tobacco, industry over-supply of low-demand markets and poor supply chain control can facilitate availability of illicit products in the marketplace83.
The literature on alcohol and tobacco tax policy in the UK focuses mainly on common measures such as duty rate changes and duty escalators. However, other tax policy options, such as structural reforms, industry measures and hypothecation, are also explored. Some, such as fully ‘specific’ or equivalent tax structures – e.g., per unit or per gram – are discussed across alcohol and tobacco. Others, such as multi-rate structural reforms and industry subsidies relate mainly to alcohol, while industry levies, price caps and minimum excise taxes are mainly discussed in relation to tobacco. The explanation for this difference is likely to lie in the different configuration of objectives and mediating factors for alcohol versus tobacco tax policy in the UK. Each of them share changing affordability, improving health, reducing health inequalities and raising revenue as objectives. However, in terms of consumption, alcohol interventions are focused on reducing harmful consumption, while tobacco control aims to reduce the prevalence of smoking (i.e., encourage quitting, reduce uptake). Tax policy narratives identified as influencing policy decisions reflect this difference. Dominant alcohol narratives described in the literature focus on harmful versus moderate drinkers and relative acceptance of the role of the alcohol industry. Those for tobacco are characterised by universal acceptance of the harms of smoking and exclusion of the tobacco industry from policy debates.
Thus, a rich seam of evidence and ideas relating to alcohol and tobacco tax policy options exists for the UK. These are summarised in Extended data35. and have been used to directly inform the SYNTAX project: firstly, informing the development of the qualitative interview topic guide and briefing for interview participants127; second, in modelling alcohol and tobacco tax options in the later part of the SYNTAX project. In terms of gaps in the evidence base, the relatively small volume of peer-reviewed literature on industry measures and hypothecation mechanisms is worthy of note. Further, while structural reform is a common theme for discussion, the associated literature presents mainly modelling-based research, rather than real-world evidence, and reports reflect uncertainty generated by Britain’s exit from the EU ('Brexit'). Following Brexit, the UK Government has introduced structural changes to the duty structure for alcohol products, creating a standardised series of tax bands based on alcohol by volume and introducing tax relief for small producers and on products sold in the on-trade venues, such as pubs28. These changes to the alcohol tax system provide an opportunity to collect real-world evidence on its impacts. For tobacco tax, Brexit gives the UK more freedom to change the level and structure of tax on tobacco products, e.g. the UK could move to a fully specific system of taxation, and Brexit could also allow the UK to directly regulate tobacco pricing by the use of policies such as minimum unit pricing128.
Few sources discussed alcohol and tobacco tax-related policies in the same space, except in general policy terms, and no research has yet attempted to model the interactions between alcohol and tobacco production, consumption and tax policy in the way proposed in our previous work7. This previous work reported the findings of a workshop on the joint tobacco–alcohol policy system with UK academics and policy professionals. The findings illustrated the need to model the effects of policies that target tobacco and/or alcohol consumption in common terms because this allows fair comparisons between the effects of changes to tobacco policy and alcohol policy. Furthermore, to understand the effects of policy changes on socio-economic or health inequalities, it is important to understand how changes to tobacco and alcohol policy might affect individuals differently, thinking particularly of the characteristics of people who both smoke and drink to harmful levels. The tobacco and alcohol fields tend to operate in substance specific research which, while acknowledging the links between these two behaviours and their determinants, rarely looks at the two issues together. This is particularly important given the comorbidity and multiplicative risks of alcohol and tobacco consumption, particularly in relation to cancer129,130. It is also important give evidence of similarities between the practices and tactics of the alcohol and tobacco industries131.
From this review of the literature, there is clear demand for conceptualising and understanding tax policy within its wider context as ‘tax and spend’, rather than solely as a means of raising revenue. There is also a debate to be had about whether this is then interpreted as a Pigouvian tax system which aims to meet the costs of externalities of product use and/or as a hypothecated public health tax system which aims to invest in prevention and treatment. In order to take this debate forward, there is more work to be done to understand the more complex landscape of policy options described in this review and how they may interact with and fit with each other. At present, it is very unclear from the literature what ‘effective’ combinations of policy options might look like, and these are likely to vary depending on the policy objective(s) being prioritised.
Tax has been shown to be among the most effective ways to change consumption of harmful commodities132–134. For those readers interested in a global overview of alcohol and tobacco tax options, it is worth looking at Chaloupka et al.,135. The paper covers a similar spread of policy options and concludes that excise taxes are a ‘powerful tool’ for reducing tobacco use and excessive drinking and that their potential to ‘significantly reduce consumption and save lives remains high’. The scope of our review was purposefully restricted to papers which focused wholly or partly on the UK. This was to ensure that the review’s findings were both relevant to the UK’s policy context and manageable within the timeframe available to deliver the review. To address this limitation, the SYNTAX project’s International Advisory Panel were invited to comment on the findings. They flagged a number of relevant complementary examples from around the world that we outline below in relation to the four policy themes identified in this review:
First, on tobacco excise duty rates, combining a high tax floor, an escalator and occasional surprise large tax increases is thought to be an effective way to reduce consumption20. Tax increases are expected to have a progressive rather than regressive impact because tobacco consumption is higher among people with lower socio-economic status who also have greater price sensitivity135.
Second, on tax structures, evidence from Sweden has shown that a shift to a tax strategy based on alcohol strength led to an increase in floor prices and a substantial reduction in consumption of the cheaper segment of the market136,137. In addition, there is evidence from Australia that the reach of differential tax rate for beers is highly dependent on the thresholds set for each tax tier138.
Third, on industry measures, taxing inputs, such as materials or labour, might also reduce industry profitability. For alcohol and tobacco, our review identified options such as levies that take money from the industries to help reduce the societal costs of their products. However, due to the perceived social and economic importance of alcohol in contrast to tobacco, policy options also discussed supporting pubs and small breweries. More work is needed to understand the influence of the price elasticity of demand for alcohol and tobacco products on the potential for industry measures to raise revenue for government given that the industry might pass the costs onto consumers. It is also unclear how tax changes on alcohol and tobacco products could affect the wider economy via impacts on the labour market and productivity across multiple sectors.
Fourth, on hypothecation, New Zealand, the USA and Canada all offer examples of hypothecation of a fixed tax on alcohol. New Zealand funded the Alcohol Advisory Council (ALAC); Washington State has funded alcohol-related research; and Québec funds Edu Alcool, a not-for-profit education and prevention organisation. There is also research on the relative acceptability of hypothecated versus across-the-board taxes showing that the former is more popular139. In terms of equity, using revenues to fund programmes that benefit the poor increases their progressive impact, as in the Philippines’ universal healthcare programme which is funded by tobacco taxes135. In terms of effectiveness, the case of tobacco shows that the market share of the illicit trade tends to be lower in jurisdictions with higher tax rates, particularly where tax administration and enforcement is effective135. This indicates that the effectiveness of tax policy could be enhanced by hypothecating tax revenue for the enforcement of tax regulations.
The strengths of the study lie, first, in the rapid but systematic approach which has been rigorously followed140. This approach allowed the review to capture the extent and nature of the work that had been produced on alcohol and tobacco tax policy options relevant to the UK in 2018, which we used as part of the progression of research in the SYNTAX project. The review findings were used to prepare to speak to alcohol and tobacco tax experts about the options for changing tax on alcohol and tobacco, which we did in 2018. Thus, whilst the 2018 end date of the search is a limitation of the study because it means that the study does not capture evidence published from 2018 to the date of publishing in 2023, as the review formed part of the larger SYNTAX project, the rapid scoping review methodology instrumentally enabled progression of the research. It facilitated the project team’s understanding of the literature and allowed us to consider tax options, not only in relation to their broad characteristics, but also with reference to technical detail, objectives, evidence of effects and mediators.
The SYNTAX research project’s focus on tax policies meant that non-tax price measures such as minimum unit pricing fell outside the scope of the review, even though tax and non-tax price measures are often intrinsically linked in policy discussions. In terms of limitations of the methodology, the review did not critically appraise the literature and embraced a variety of sources that may have been excluded from a more traditional systematic review, e.g. policy briefings and model-based predictions. However, this decision is in line with recommended best practice for rapid scoping reviews31,32. It is mitigated somewhat in this case by the research team’s recording and reporting of types of sources, research funding and methods used. In doing so, the review reflects the nature of both peer-reviewed evidence and the wider policy debate on alcohol and tobacco taxation discussed in the grey literature. It also responds to the need identified by Parkhurst and Abeysinghe to think about evidence quality in terms of appropriateness as well as rigor in relation to evidence-based policy as opposed to evidence-based medicine141.
This review has clearly identified a contemporary set of policy objectives, interventions and related mediating factors that were summarised in a briefing to alcohol and tobacco tax policy stakeholders ahead of interviews for the SYNTAX project about the options for changing tax on alcohol and tobacco127. The differences between alcohol and tobacco tax interventions and debates suggest an opportunity for cross-policy learning. There is currently little literature/evidence which considers joint effects of tax options for alcohol and tobacco, despite evidence that co-consumption multiplies risks to health. Modelling the impact of these alcohol and tobacco policy options to better understand their relative impact would provide information to help decide among the available options.
Figshare: SYNTAX Rapid Scoping Review: PRISMA Scoping Review checklist and Supplementary Information
https://doi.org/10.15131/shef.data.2203264435
This project contains the following underlying data:
Figshare: PRISMA checklist for ‘Options for modifying UK alcohol and tobacco tax: A rapid scoping review of the evidence over the period 1997–2018’. https://doi.org/10.15131/shef.data.2203264435.
Data are available under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International license (CC-BY 4.0).
Our thanks to the wider SYNTAX project team and advisory board for their input on this scoping review.
Competing Interests: No competing interests were disclosed.
Reviewer Expertise: Health economics; economics of health behaviours
Competing Interests: No competing interests were disclosed.
Reviewer Expertise: Health taxes, commercial determinants of health & political economy analysis
Are the rationale for, and objectives of, the Systematic Review clearly stated?
Yes
Are sufficient details of the methods and analysis provided to allow replication by others?
Yes
Is the statistical analysis and its interpretation appropriate?
Not applicable
Are the conclusions drawn adequately supported by the results presented in the review?
Partly
References
1. Burton R, Henn C, Lavoie D, O'Connor R, et al.: A rapid evidence review of the effectiveness and cost-effectiveness of alcohol control policies: an English perspective.Lancet. 2017; 389 (10078): 1558-1580 PubMed Abstract | Publisher Full TextCompeting Interests: No competing interests were disclosed.
Reviewer Expertise: Health economics; economics of health behaviours
Are the rationale for, and objectives of, the Systematic Review clearly stated?
Yes
Are sufficient details of the methods and analysis provided to allow replication by others?
Yes
Is the statistical analysis and its interpretation appropriate?
Not applicable
Are the conclusions drawn adequately supported by the results presented in the review?
Yes
Competing Interests: No competing interests were disclosed.
Reviewer Expertise: Health taxes, commercial determinants of health & political economy analysis
Alongside their report, reviewers assign a status to the article:
Invited Reviewers | ||
---|---|---|
1 | 2 | |
Version 3 (revision) 30 Oct 23 |
read | |
Version 2 (revision) 03 Oct 23 |
read | read |
Version 1 16 May 23 |
read | read |
Provide sufficient details of any financial or non-financial competing interests to enable users to assess whether your comments might lead a reasonable person to question your impartiality. Consider the following examples, but note that this is not an exhaustive list:
Sign up for content alerts and receive a weekly or monthly email with all newly published articles
Register with NIHR Open Research
Already registered? Sign in
If you are a previous or current NIHR award holder, sign up for information about developments, publishing and publications from NIHR Open Research.
We'll keep you updated on any major new updates to NIHR Open Research
The email address should be the one you originally registered with F1000.
You registered with F1000 via Google, so we cannot reset your password.
To sign in, please click here.
If you still need help with your Google account password, please click here.
You registered with F1000 via Facebook, so we cannot reset your password.
To sign in, please click here.
If you still need help with your Facebook account password, please click here.
If your email address is registered with us, we will email you instructions to reset your password.
If you think you should have received this email but it has not arrived, please check your spam filters and/or contact for further assistance.
Comments on this article Comments (0)